The Grossman model

The central proposition of the Grossman model (Grossman 1972) is that health can be viewed as a durable capital stock that produces an output of healthy time. It is assumed that individuals inherit an initial stock of health that depreciates with age and can be increased by investment. The model is similar to human capital…

Single payer = single data point

Bernie Sanders and others are advocating a Medicare for All system.  At first glance this is a sensible approach.  Why not allow the government to provide equitable health insurance coverage for all?  Don’t we want to let all Americans have high quality care?  Why not use the power of the federal government to help negotiate…

Surrogate Outcomes and the Prentice Criteria

Clinical trials aim to measure how different treatments affect outcomes of interest to patients.  In many cases, however, measuring the ultimate outcomes of interest proves logistically difficult.  For instance, measuring overall survival for some oncology patients may be impractical if survival for the standard of care is long since the required time and expense to…

Will price transparency reduce prices?

Economic theory would say that in normal markets, the answer is yes. When prices are widely known, suppliers can compete on prices–as well as quality–and markets become more efficient. In the health care setting, however, a key question is ‘which price’? For hospital services, patients are the ultimate consumers of the service and do pay…

What is MCDA and why do we need it?

Value measurement using cost-effectiveness analysis (CEA) is one of the core stables of health economic research.  CEA often uses quality adjusted life years (QALYs) to capture how a treatment affects a patients mortality and morbidity.  CEA makes explicit assumptions about the tradeoffs between mortality and morbidity by assuming these are additive.  Further, this approach, however,…